1. Is Our Country as Good as Our Athletes Are?
The New York Times AUG. 19, 2016
Pessimism
has flavored this election campaign. America is in decline. The country is on
the wrong track. We’re getting our clocks cleaned in global trade deals. We’re
still suffering from the humiliation of Iraq.
The
share of Americans who say that democracy is a “fairly bad” or “very bad”
system of government is rising sharply. A quarter of young Americans feel that
way, according to data drawn from the World Values Survey. A majority of young
Americans believe that the United States should stay out of world affairs,
according to a Chicago Council on Global Affairs report.
Yet
when you watch the Olympics, we don’t seem like some sad-sack country in
terminal decline. If anything, the coverage gets a little boring because we’re
always winning! And the winners have such amazingly American stories and
personality types (Biles, Ledecky, and, yes, Lochte).
American
Olympic performance has been astoundingly consistent over the recent decades.
With rare exception, we can be counted on to win between 101 and 110 medals
Olympiad after Olympiad. The 2016 team seems on pace to win at least that many.
We’re
not great when measured by medals per capita (New Zealand, Denmark, Hungary,
Australia and Britain are the big winners there), but America does have more
medals than any other nation in history, and that lead is widening.
Moreover,
America doesn’t win because we have better athletes (talent must be distributed
equally). America does well because it has such great systems for preparing
athletes. Medals are won by institutions as much as by individuals. The Germans
have a great system for training kayakers, equestrians and throwers — the
discus or javelin. The U.S. has amazing institutions to prepare jumpers,
swimmers, basketball players, gymnasts, runners and decathletes.
The
big question is: Is the greatness of America’s sports institutions reflective
of the country’s strong institutions generally, or is it more like the Soviet
Union’s sports greatness, a Potemkin show masking national rot?
Well,
if you step outside the pall of the angry campaign rhetoric, you see that
America’s institutions are generally quite strong. Over the past decades, some
developing countries, like Brazil, India and China, posted glitzy economic
growth numbers. But those countries are now all being hampered by institutional
weakness and growth is plummeting.
But
America’s economic success is like our Olympic success, writ large. The
nation’s troubles are evident, but our country has sound fundamentals. The
American dollar is by far the world’s currency. The Food and Drug
Administration is the benchmark for medical standards. The American patent system
is the most important in the world.
Nine
of Forbes’s 10 most valuable brands are American (Apple, Google, IBM and so
on). The U.S. is the leading energy producer. We have 15 (at least!) of the
world’s top 20 universities, while Hollywood is as dominant as ever.
2. Turkey: Let's close the chapter of coups
The government should have a well-developed plan for dealing with the
country's major issues.
Since
the failed coup attempt, Turkey has been struggling to deal with the
aftershock, grieving for the loss of more than 250 lives and caring for more
than 2,000 who have been injured.
The
country, however, has emerged more cohesive, with shows of unity across almost
the entire spectrum of political and social classes.
Turkey's
overcentralised administrative system creates an incentive for groups first to
increase their presence within the state apparatus and then to dominate it
Political classes of all stripes have rejected the
coup attempt by the rogue Gulenist network, which has been designated as a
terrorist organisation by Turkey since 2014, and celebrated the nation's sense
of ownership of Turkey's democracy, which contributed to the failure of the
attempted coup.
All these are encouraging. The nation's sense of
ownership and the maturity of the political classes underpin Turkey's
democracy.
Overcentralisation
These are necessary but not sufficient conditions for
permanently closing the door on the age of coups, and terminating the shady and
illegal activities of rogue elements within the state. More is needed.
Three measures in particular are vital to achieving a
coup-free political future for the country and disincentivising any rogue group
seeking first to dominate state institutions, and then to abuse the power that
it acquires through this domination for its own parochial group agenda.
Structurally, the overcentralised nature of the
Turkish state makes it easier for the would-be coup plotters to achieve their
goals and for a well-organised rogue element to exercise a disproportionate
level of power.
Ideologically, Turkey's overcentralised and
ideologically proactive state creates incentives for sociopolitical or
religious groups to seek a presence within it and influence it through public
institutions and state machinery in order to fulfil their sociopolitical
designs for the state and society at large.
Politically - or in terms of political culture
- the lack of proper political interaction, dialogue and problem-solving
mechanisms between the ruling parties and other opposition groups has paved the
way for actors to gain a non-democratic foothold in the political sphere and
acquire political power, which they have invariably abused.
Whether
out of necessity or by choice, whenever Turkey's current and previous
governments have opted for a partner to deal with major challenges or
impending crises, they have chosen their partner from outside the parliament
and political sphere.
|
Turkey's overcentralised administrative system creates an incentive for groups first to increase their
presence within the state apparatus and then to dominate it.
In most indicators of centralisation, Turkey is far
above the OECD average. For instance, the central
government collects almost 70 percent of total revenues, far more
than the OECD average of 58 percent (PDF).
Even more strikingly, 85 percent of public
servants work
for the central governmentin Turkey, while only 15 percent work in local
government. This is the highest ratio among OECD countries.
Disproportionate power
In an overcentralised system, it is relatively easier
for certain groups to wield disproportionate power over the system.
Once you control key positions in some of the key
institutions, you can project influence incommensurate with your actual size or
support. The case of the Gulenist network and its actions within the state
machinery confirm this point.
As a corollary, decentralisation will by default tame
the ambition of groups seeking to infiltrate and dominate the system, as the
number of institutions, and the geographic and administrative distribution of
these institutions, will be more numerous and wider. The state's power will not
be concentrated in the centre. Instead, it will be more defuse.
Moreover, this overcentralised state is also extremely
proactive in attempting to influence the identity and ideology of its society
through social engineering.
For a long time, the Turkish state
encouraged a preferred identity of secular,Western-oriented nationalism, while
securitising the Kurdish and Islamist identities.
Those whose identity was securitised believed that the
only way to change this was through gaining access to the levers of power
within the state structure.
Such a belief - coupled with the nature of
the state - gave the state apparatus a strong pull factor for any
group that aspired to make its imprint on public life.
In this respect, the Gulenist network was partially
the product of Turkey's authoritarian, overly centralised Kemalist state.
The government should take a lesson from this experience, and strive to make
the state blind to identities and remainideologically neutral.
3.
How to Make Child Care Affordable
The Bloomberg AUG 19, 2016
Donald
Trump and Hillary Clinton agree on this much: The federal government should do
more to help families pay for child care.
They’re
surely right. In many parts of the U.S., putting children in a day-care center
has become the single greatest expense parents face, exceeding
the cost of housing. And it’s growing: From 2009 to 2016, the cost of child
care and nursery school jumped 21 percent, nearly twice
the rate of inflation overall.
Trump’s
proposed solution is to allow parents to deduct
the average cost of child care from their taxes. That may sound like a
generous offer, and it would indeed be expensive.
The trouble is, it would do nothing for families most in need of help. After
all, the median household pays just
$9,000 in federal taxes; 45
percent pay no federal income tax at all. (Trump’s campaign says he
will also extend the deduction to half
of payroll taxes, and will provide details about this plan
later on.)
In
theory, Clinton’s strategy would help many more families. She promises to limit
the amount parents pay for child care to 10 percent of their income. But her
campaign hasn’t
said how she would achieve that goal, or at what cost.
Some
expansion in federal assistance is certainly
needed. The existing income-tax credit for child care costs is limited to
$600 to $1,050 per child, depending on income.
Yet
the average price of home day care for an infant ranges from almost
$5,000 a year in Tennessee and South Carolina to twice that in
Florida, New York and Massachusetts. Child-care centers are typically even more
expensive: In many states, the annual cost to cover an infant and a
four-year-old together is more than $20,000.
Beyond
enlarging the tax credits, the federal government should pay them in advance --
much as Obamacare provides
subsidies for health insurance premiums at the time they need to be paid. And
as with Obamacare subsidies, child-care tax credits should be paid directly
from the government to child-care centers.
The
Center for American Progress has proposed such
an approach. Its plan would offer tax credits of as much as $14,000 per child,
and limit families’ spending on child care to 12 percent of their income.
Any
changes in federal policy would do well to also raise the
qualityof child care. The country’s 285,000 child care workers earn less than $21,000 a year on
average; even so, only a third of infant care settings meet the staffing ratios
that experts recommend. And more than one-third of workers at home-based
child care centers have only a high school degree or less. While a
four-year college degree isn’t always required, workers ideally should
study child development and early childhood education -- courses offered
at many community colleges.
Trump’s
child-care tax deduction wouldn’t directly affect quality. Clinton says she
would improve things with a separate effort to subsidize the pay of child care
workers. A better approach would be to also give day care centers an incentive
to perform well. Louisiana, for example, gives them a tax credit tied to
their state quality
rating. It also gives child care workers a separate credit that increases
with the amount of training they complete.
Another
approach is to make it easier for parents to get information about staff
training before enrolling their children in a day-care center.
Of
course, none of these strategies would be cheap. CAP says its tax credit
proposal would cost taxpayers $40 billion annually. But kids who get quality
day care at an early age often do
better in school, and their parents are more
likely to work. These benefits could be well worth the price.
沒有留言:
張貼留言